Addiction, Ground Rents, and Urban Casino Development
By Martin Young and
Francis Markham
How to cite:
Young M., & Markham F. (2020). Addiction, Ground Rents, and Urban Casino Development. Critical Gambling Studies, 6. https://doi.org/10.29173/cgs27
Casino development has
become a favoured urban development strategy in a number of
post-industrialising western economies (Hannigan, 2007). These developments are
often justified on the basis that casinos
attract reputedly rich and super-rich consumers
from other places in what amounts to a rather convenient geographical transfer
of value. These wealthy consumers, so the mercantilist argument goes, enrich
both the casino owners and the broader public through taxes and license fees.
Moreover, these gambling dollars are imported, while the effects and responsibility
for problem gambling, one of the key arguments against gambling developments,
are conveniently exported. A second argument, particularly favoured by the
gambling industry and other casino proponents, is the creation of local jobs,
both in construction and subsequent casino operations. For example, the
Canadian casino operator Gateway Casino and Entertainment has organised its new
casino proposal for London, Canada, around
the creation of 700 local jobs. More generally, neoclassical economists suggest
that casinos tend to increase economic growth in the longer-term (e.g. Walker,
2007). A third argument is that casinos bring a certain symbolic value to a
city, particularly if they take the form of large towers such as Barangaroo,
Sydney, or its proposed competitor in Star City Casino located across the
harbour in Pyrmont.
However, none of these
explanations adequately explain why casinos
in particular are so important to the contemporary development strategies
of so many capitalist cities, especially since wide-spread casino
liberalisation has made attracting lucrative high-rollers increasingly
competitive. Casinos can only attract consumers from other places when legal
casinos are not widespread. In the
presence of extensive legalisation, urban spatial monopolies are broken and
gamblers can gamble at home. Thus, while the strategy of casino-led urban development
was feasible for Las Vegas and Macau, it cannot simply be replicated elsewhere,
as the dwindling fortunes of Atlantic City have shown (Peck, 2016; Peck, 2017). Furthermore, urban
casinos rely on addicted, local gambling-machine players
for the lion’s share of their profits in many locations. Similarly, casinos are
notoriously small employers relative to their income, providing fewer jobs even
than the hospitality sector in general. And symbolic architecture could
arguably be better accomplished if not constrained by the distinctive
architectural requirements of casino operators.
We argue that there is
another, more important, reason that casinos are especially well-suited to
urban development agendas – and that is their linkage to ground rents. Here it
is useful to deviate into a less-known area of political economic theory,
namely the way in which, according to Marxian theory, surplus profits are transformed
into ground rents. For Marx (1981 [1894]: 914),
ground rents are payments by capitalists to landowners simply for their
permission to use the land for some productive purpose:
All
this means in actual fact is that, under the given conditions, the ownership of
these square feet of land enables the landowner to seize a certain amount of
unpaid labour, which capital has realized by rooting in the soil like a pig in
potatoes.
This means that
landowners draw off a part of the profits from commodity production simply by
right of their ownership of landed property. The reason rents can be extracted,
according to Marx, is that landed property forms the necessary basis of all
production and consumption, and its ownership by a particular class means that
profits needed to be shared with this group if any production is to be
possible.
However, there is one
form of rent that Marx argues only occurs under special circumstances - a form
of rent he termed monopoly rent. Here
it is high buyer demand for a commodity of limited supply that drives the
market price of the commodity above its value. The owner of the land used to
produce the commodity is able to commandeer a portion of these surplus profits
as monopoly rent. Marx (1981 [1894]: 910-911)
provides the famous example of a vineyard producing a special vintage wine:
By monopoly price here we mean any price
determined simply by the desire and ability of the buyer to pay, independently of
the price of the product as determined by price of production and value. A
vineyard bears a monopoly price if it produces wine which is of quite
exceptional quality but can be produced only in a relatively small quantity. By
virtue of this monopoly price, the wine-grower whose excess over the value of
his product is determined purely and simply by the wealth and the preference of
fashionable wine-drinkers can realize a substantial surplus profit. This
surplus profit, which in this case flows from a monopoly price, is transformed
into rent and accrues in this form to the landowner by virtue of his title to
the portion of the earth endowed with these special properties. Here,
therefore, the monopoly price creates the rent.
Marx did not give much
attention to these rents in his notes (which became Capital Volume III) because they were produced by the vagaries of
supply and demand rather than the general motion of capital – the production,
circulation and supply of value – that he was primarily concerned with.
However, in more recent years, it has become clear that monopoly prices have
emerged as important basis for ground rents. David Harvey (2012), for example, has emphasised how
important these rents have become to the tourism industries and to the social construction
of places in general.
We argue that there are
two ways in which monopoly rents have become centrally important to the
gambling industries. First, casinos and other gambling venues achieve monopoly
prices for the commodities they produce because of the increased desire of
addicted consumers. Indeed, an orthodox definition of problem gambling is based
on “… difficulties in limiting money and/or time spent on gambling leading
to adverse consequences for the gambler, others, or for the community …” (Neal et al., 2005: i). In other words, the
production of gambling commodities involves what Adams and Livingstone (2015)
refer to as an ‘addiction surplus’ – an economic surplus that is generated
through over-consumption. A similar argument regarding the production of
coercive or akratic commodities is
made by Young and Markham (2017). The
surplus profits so produced increase the amount of ground rents that the
landowner of a casino site can extract as payment. In many cases, of course,
the casino operator buys the land and thus internalises this rent relation,
vastly adding to their profits.
The key point is that a
monopoly price for gambling commodities produces a quantum of ground rent
over-and-above what would be ordinarily received by non-addictive or
non-akratic forms of production or consumption. These monopoly rents are highly
sought by landowners who engage in the rent-seeking
behaviour associated with casino development
interests. We would argue that this ability for casinos to produce monopoly
rents is one reason they are uniquely attractive to an ensemble of urban actors
with vested property interests.
While monopoly rents produced via addiction could
explain why casino land becomes more
valuable, urban casino development
in recent years has tended to take place on prime public land, whether that be
the waterfront of Singapore or Sydney. In other words, casinos have been built
on land that was already amongst the most
valuable in the world. These prime urban locations
already bear a very high potential monopoly rent. Or more precisely, it is land
that would be highly valuable if it were able to be brought into private
ownership and bought and sold on the market given that the price of land is
derived from “expectations of future rents” (Harvey, 2012: 28). Consequently,
this land is highly desired by multiple potential buyers (e.g. for luxury
residential or commercial uses) who have an ability to pay underwritten by
access to global finance markets. The main problem for developers is that this
is often public land under state control and not released to the market, in
part because of its importance to the city as a whole.
Casino development is one way around this. Casino urbanism with its promise of jobs,
economic development and high-rollers landing in private jets provides
rhetorical cover for the appropriation of prime public space by gambling
capital. This ‘new enclosure’ of the most valuable public land in a city is
premised on the necessity of these prime locations for the success of a casino.
But casino
developments are rarely only casino
developments. They often include private apartment towers and retail spaces
which are sold at
very high prices.
In these cases, urban casino developments rely on what is essentially real estate
development to underwrite their profitability, furnishing the “real estate
state” (Stein, 2019) with an excuse to facilitate private property development in
desirable urban locations. Whether this occurs through the privatisation of
public lands or through tweaks to or exemptions from urban planning rules, vast
financial wealth is created through the production of an anticipated stream of
future ground rents. The astronomical land prices that these developments are
able to command are, of course, a function of the captured monopoly ground
rents.
These two expressions
of monopoly rent, one that increases the value of land through addictive
gambling, the other that appropriates prime land under the guise of necessary
urban development, are cumulative and interactive. Addiction
or akrasia-generated rents are likely to apply to all gambling venues to
various degrees including those in prime urban locations. And the discursive
logics of casino capital will continue to be employed to enclose and appropriate
the most valuable urban locations as a neoliberal form of real estate
development.
State power is
necessary to the production of both strands of this monopoly rents project.
State power needs to be activated in order to provide the necessary planning and
regulatory permissions for casino developments. The state also acts to
privatise and sell-off urban space to the gambling industries, as well as
through the provision of a planning system which balances the competing needs
of different fractions of capital for access to urban land. This occurs even in
the face of documented gambling harms partly because the state powers have been
captured by gambling and real estate interests, and partly because the state is
a direct beneficiary of increased land prices (via higher land taxes) and sale
fees for the land itself. For these reasons, the state tends to allow gambling
harm to rise to the maximum level that civil society will tolerate, relegating
gambling-related public-health to a largely discursive and abrogative affair
(Young & Markham, 2017). Indeed, urban land development strategies, such as
the ones outlined at the start of this article, are predicated on the
maintenance of high levels of gambling harm as their necessary
precondition.
We have outlined, in an
abstract and stylised way, two mechanisms through which ground rents are
corralled by urban casino developers to reap windfall profits. However, casino
developments take place in concrete urban geographies rather than the abstract
space of political economy, and thus intersect with other forms of social
domination, particularly race. Racialisation crosscuts the economic geographies
of urban casino development. The dominant racial trope evoked when urban
casinos are promoted as attracting an international clientele is the “Chinese
high roller”. These figures are simultaneously constructed as clever
entrepreneurs (and thus able to lose large fortunes without suffering harm) and
as useful idiots amenable to fleecing. This expression of “Orientalism” (Said, 1979),
designed to legitimate what would otherwise be seen a form of exploitation, should
not be surprising. Mercantilism, after all, is the economics of empire, and it
is hardly the first time that colonial logics have justified the export of
harmful and addictive commodities from the West to China (Lowe, 2015).
However, in settler colonies
like Australia where race is produced primarily through the expropriation of
land rather than relations of slavery (Wolfe, 2016), and where dispossession
rather than proletarianisation is the dominant form of oppression for
Indigenous peoples (Coulthard, 2014), questions of land rights and sovereignty
always haunt discussions of rent. Here, the ‘public’ lands privatised via
casino developments have been violently wrested from Indigenous peoples. Ground
rents are extracted from stolen Indigenous land. In this context, the
extraction of surplus profits not only implicates relationships between
gamblers and casino capitalists, and capitalists and landlords, but also, in
settler colonial states, operates through the expropriative relationship
between settlers and Indigenous peoples. This violent ‘primitive accumulation’
is the necessary condition for contemporary colonial forms of ground rent
extraction (Coulthard, 2014; Marx, 1976 [1867]).
Yet
the reality that cities are in fact Country is rarely remembered among settler
scholars (Porter, 2018). If Indigenous peoples are remembered in public debate
about urban casinos, they largely figure as vulnerable subjects, defined by
perceived psychological deficits and subject to forms of racialized and
paternalist government policy designed to prevent dangerous consumption
(Nicoll, 2018). Any benefits Indigenous people receive from casino development
in Australia come through the largess of casino magnates who may elect to
target Indigenous people for employment in their businesses as an act of
‘reconciliation’ (Nicoll, 2018). But the irrefutable fact of the theft of
Indigenous land further complicates the question of ground rent, for it raises
the question of its just re-distribution. While the debt of unpaid reparations
remains to be counted or repaid, decades-old demands for settlers to “pay
the rent” will continue colour questions of ground
rent in settler-colonial contexts.
References
Adams PJ and
Livingstone C. 2015. Addiction surplus: The add-on margin that makes addictive
consumptions difficult to contain. International
Journal of Drug Policy 26: 107-111.
Coulthard,
G. S. 2014. Red Skin, White Masks: Rejecting the Colonial Politics of
Recognition. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.
Harvey D. 2012. Rebel Cities: From the Right to the City to
the Urban Revolution London: Verso.
Hannigan,
J. 2007. Casino cities. Geography Compass, 1(4),
959-975.
Lowe, L. 2015. The
Intimacies of Four Continents. Durham: Duke University Press.
Marx K. 1976 [1867]. Capital: A Critique of Political Economy,
Volume 1, London: Penguin.
Marx K. 1981 [1894]. Capital: A Critique of Political Economy,
Volume 3, London: Penguin.
Neal P, Delfabbro PH
and O'Neil M. 2005. Problem Gambling and
Harm: Towards a National Definition. Melbourne: Report prepared for the
National Gambling Research Program Working Party.
Nicoll,
F. 2018. Beyond the figure of the problem gambler: Locating race and overeignty
struggles in everyday cultural spaces of gambling. Journal of Law and
Social Policy, 30(1), 127-149.
Peck J. 2016.
Transatlantic city, part 1: Conjunctural urbanism. Urban Studies. 54(1):
4-30.
Peck J. 2017.
Transatlantic city, part 2: Late entrepreneurialism. Urban Studies 54(2): 327-363.
Porter,
L. 2018. From an urban country to urban Country: Confronting the cult of denial
in Australian cities. Australian Geographer, 49(2),
239-246.
Said
EW. 1979. Orientalism, New York: Vintage.
Stein,
S. 2019. Capital City: Gentrification and the Real Estate State.
Verso Books.
Walker,
D. M. 2007. The Economics of Casino Gambling. Springer Science
& Business Media.
Wolfe, P. 2016. Traces
of History: Elementary Structures of Race. Verso Books.
Young M and Markham
F. 2017. Coercive commodities and the political economy of involuntary
consumption: The case of the gambling industries. Environment and Planning A 49: 2762-2779.
Comments
Post a Comment